ARE HOUSING PRICES, HOUSEHOLD
DEBT, AND GROWTH SUSTAINABLE?
DIMITRI B. PAPADIMITRIOU, EDWARD CHILCOTE,
and GENNARO ZEZZA*Introduction
Rising home prices and low interest rates have fueled the recent surge in mortgage borrowing and
enabled consumers to spend at high rates relative to their income. Low interest rates have counterbalanced
the growth in debt and acted to dampen the growth in household debt-service burdens.
As past Levy Institute strategic analyses have pointed out, these trends are not sustainable:
household spending relative to income cannot grow indefinitely.
In this report, we follow up on a number of points brought out in our last strategic analysis
(Godley et al. 2005).We focus on the residential real estate market and examine the effects of possible
changes in current trends in the price of real estate on the financial condition of households
and their spending behavior. After reviewing some recent perspectives on the state of housing
prices, household debt, and economic growth, we investigate the level of housing prices in relation
to rental and vacancy rates.We examine the level of debt of the household sector and show
that even with the sustained deterioration in household balance sheets, borrowing has grown radically
in recent years. Despite low interest rates the burden of servicing this debt has reached new
heights. Rising home prices have done little to improve the equity position of households, and any
fall in housing prices will worsen matters. We show that the precarious financial position of
households stems largely from loose lending standards and the heightened cash-out refinancing
of recent years. Noting that when and where housing prices have fallen, borrowing and growth
have slowed, we turn our attention to the plausible effects of a slowdown in housing prices on
household spending, economic growth, and sectoral balances.We show that the optimistic forecasts
of the Congressional Budget Office rely on sustained private-sector borrowing. We then
simulate the impact of a drop in house prices and reduced borrowing and conclude that GDP
The Levy Institute’s Macro-Modeling Team consists of Distinguished Scholar
PAPADIMITRIOU,
WYNNE GODLEY, Levy Institute President DIMITRI B.Senior Scholar ANWAR M. SHAIKH, and Research Scholars EDWARD CHILCOTE, CLAUDIO H. DOS SANTOS, andGENNARO ZEZZA
*The authors wish to acknowledge comments from Wynne Godley. All errors remain with the authors.
. All questions and correspondence should be directed to Professor Papadimitriou at 845-758-7700 or dbp@levy.org.some “local” markets.While recognizing that housing prices in
some local markets may be high, Greenspan maintains that
high real estate prices do not pose a significant risk to growth.
In March 2003, he characterized any analogy to stock market
bubbles as a “large stretch.”
Despite debt burdens that have grown dramatically in
recent years, Greenspan views the finances of households as
sound. In October 2004, he argued that measures of household
financial stress, such as the debt-service ratio and financialobligations
ratio, were not worrisome. He noted at that time
that such measures had flattened in recent years, owing to low
interest rates. While debt levels and debt-service ratios appear
high, these levels may be manageable when viewed from a
balance-sheet perspective. The higher level of assets has been
cited as evidence that the household sector is in good financial
shape and that there is still a substantial pool of available home
equity (Greenspan 2004a, 2005a).
A popular perspective on housing prices has been advanced
by Glaeser, Gyourko, and Saks (2005), who contend that limits
in supply explain the rise in housing prices in recent years. They
suggest that rising physical costs of construction, increasing land
prices, and regulatory barriers to new construction are driving
the rise in house prices. Some research at the Federal Reserve
attributes the growth in housing prices to local policies that
limit supply rather than to national policies (Del Negro and
Otrok 2005).
Yet another popular view is that demographic factors drive
demand and price trends in housing. It is thought that the relationship
between housing demand and housing prices is at
least partially tied to the generation entering its house-buying
years. With the baby-boom generation well past its initial
house-buying years and younger large demographic cohorts
only now on the verge of housebuying, the recent past is anomalous.
This suggests that the movements in recent housing
prices are not tied to demographic trends. Using demographic
data, N. Gregory Mankiw and David N.Weil (1990) mistakenly
forecasted that housing prices would fall over the period in
which they rose.
Others, such as Federal Reserve economists Jonathan
McCarthy and Richard W. Peach (2004), think houses are similar
to financial assets such as stocks and bonds and are valued
accordingly. They contend that the low nominal mortgage
interest rates justify current housing prices (2004, p. 6). But if
it is true that home prices are valued by the discounted present
2
Strategic Analysis, January 2006growth will slow. We anticipate that as the private-sector balance
improves, and the foreign-sector balance stabilizes, the
government deficit will grow. In our last scenario we explore
the possibility of offsetting the reduced private-sector demand
with increased government spending to maintain existing
growth and employment levels.We show that if private expenditures
slow, the government deficit must grow to maintain
existing employment and growth rates, implying a growing
foreign deficit.
Housing Prices
Previous Levy Institute reports (Shaikh et al. 2003; Papadimitriou
et al. 2002) and other economists, such Baker (2002), Case et al.
(2004), and Leamer (2003), have been warning for some time
that housing was excessively priced. Our October 2003
Strategic Analysis (Shaikh et al. 2003), for example, showed the
housing price-to-earnings ratio to be above its previous peak in
1989 and close to its peak in 1979. Since that time, housing
prices have further appreciated.
Many central bankers around the world have viewed the
run-up in housing prices cautiously. They see the world economy
as vulnerable to an economic slowdown and increasingly
prone to financial instability because of inflated home prices.
For years they have seen the increase in housing prices contributing
to large financial imbalances and have openly spoken
of bubbles bursting and asset prices falling (Srejber 2002;
Bollard 2004). They note that house price appreciation has permitted
consumer-spending growth to outstrip income growth.
They identify the consumption made possible by mortgage
equity withdrawal as a key factor driving recent economic
growth (Large 2004). Federal Reserve Governor Donald Kohn
(2005) has also spoken openly about the unsustainability of
spending imbalances and “asset-price anomalies,” but differs in
his perspective on its resolution.
While a few domestic economists and some foreign central
bankers have been warning about the dangers of housing price
bubbles for years, Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan
has disputed its existence. As late as October 2004, Greenspan
was adamant that a national housing bubble did not exist and
was unlikely to form. He argued that the nature of the residential
real estate market, with its large transactions costs, impedes
speculative trading and restrains the development of price
bubbles. More recently he noted the possibility of “froth” in
value of forecasted future net income flows, with the current
interest rates used for discounting, then even modest increases
in interest rates should induce large declines in housing prices.
According to many indicators, houses are overpriced. For
instance, consider the price-to-rent ratio—the price of a house
divided by its rent. The Joint Center for Housing Studies publishes
data on median homebuyer costs and median renter
contract costs. Figure 1 shows the price-to-annualized-rent
ratio in the United States from 1976 to 2004, providing a useful
reference point for evaluating when home prices appear
high and low.
home today is improving faster than the measured
quality of renter-occupied homes, as McCarthy and Peach
(2004, p.7) suggest, then this measure may overstate the movement
in the prices of homes relative to the rent they bring in.
The price-to-rent ratio
to just over 20 in 2004. There appears to be a cyclical pattern
until the late 1990s. The past data suggest that the national
housing cycle should take eight to ten years and the half cycle
should last four to six years.
Given the patterns seen in the late 1970s, 1980s, and early
1990s, we would have expected the price-to-rent ratio to have
turned in the late 1990s. From the trough of 1993 to the still
unknown peak, more than 12 years have passed. Based on previous
patterns, the turning point is at least seven years overdue.
The price-to-rent ratio in 2004 was 34 percent higher
than the trough in 1993 and 24 percent higher than the last
highest peak in 1979. Furthermore, housing prices appreciated
in 2005.
In the peaks and troughs of the last two cycles, housing
prices have been characterized by overshooting. On the upside,
mortgage lenders may be too lenient.Whatever the factors that
contribute to the momentum that leads to overshooting in
housing prices, adjustments typically occur over four- to fiveyear
periods.
The price-to-rent ratio is affected by either the movement
in home prices or that in rents. In order for the ratio to fall,
either home prices must fall or rents must rise.
Renters do not have much room to make additional rental
payments. The Federal Reserve publishes a series called the
financial-obligations ratio (FOR) for renters, which is an estimate
of debt-service payments and financial obligations
divided by the disposable personal income of renters. As Figure
2 shows, during the 1980s the financial-obligations ratio for
1 If the measured quality of the median owneroccupied2 increased from just under 14 in 1985The Levy Economics Institute of Bard College
3renters ranged from 22.35 percent to 26.55 percent. During the
1990s, the FOR for renters rose from 24.65 percent in the first
quarter of 1990 to 29.41 percent in the last quarter of 1999. In
the last five years, the FOR for renters has ranged from 28.87
percent to 31.75 percent. In the third quarter of 2005, the ratio
stood at 28.87 percent. This suggests that while renters may be
able to manage modest increases in rent, they do not have the
disposable income necessary to make appreciably higher rental
payments.
Moreover, residential landlords have less power to raise
rents today than in the past because vacancy rates are at historic
highs. In the 1970s and 1980s, vacancy rates, as shown in
Figure 3, varied from 5 percent to 7.7 percent. In the 1990s,
vacancy rates varied from 7.2 percent to 8.1 percent. In the last
five years, vacancy rates have climbed steadily from around
8 percent in 2000 to near 10 percent in 2005, which suggests
that the stock of rental housing exceeds demand. The rental
market favors renters.
The prices of homes depend largely on the effective demand
for them. The affordability index of the National Association of
13
15
17
19
21
1976 1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004
Figure 1
Housing Price-to-Rent RatioPrice-to-Rent Ratio
Sources:
Joint Center for Housing Studies of Harvard University and U.S. Bureauo
f Labor StatisticsSource:
Federal ReserveFigure 2
Financial-Obligations Ratio of Renters20
24
28
32
1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004
Financial-Obligations of Renters
4
Strategic Analysis, January 20060
40
80
120
1955 1961 1967 1973 1979 1985 1991 1997 2003
Figure 4
Disposable Income Ratios
Household-Sector Debt and Mortgage Debt toSource:
Household Debt to Disposable Income
Household Mortgage Debt to Disposable Income
Percent of Disposable Income
Federal Reserve Flow of Funds0
4
8
12
16
1955 1961 1967 1973 1979 1985 1991 1997 2003
Source:
Federal Reserve Flow of FundsFigure 5
Disposable Income
Household-Sector Borrowing as Percent ofP
ercent of Disposable Income10
11
12
13
14
1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004
Source:
Federal ReserveFigure 6
Debt-Service RatioD
ebt-Service Ratio3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
1955 1961 1967 1973 1979 1985 1991 1997 2003
Figure 7
Ratio
Household-Sector Financial-Asset-to-LiabilitySource:
Federal Reserve Flow of Funds4
6
8
10
1972 1976 1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004
Figure 3
Rental Vacancy RatesVacancy Rate (Percent)
Source:
U.S. Bureau of the CensusRealtors has fallen in the last three years (2005). In August
2005, it reached its lowest point since September 1991. This has
occurred while mortgage rates fell to their lowest levels in
decades. High prices, high vacancy rates, and low affordability
suggest that it is unlikely that home prices will continue to
appreciate at recent rates.
Financial Condition of the Household Sector
3The debt burden of U.S. households continues to rise. For the
decades of the 1960s and 1970s, the compound annual growth
rate of debt to income increased by less than 1 percent.
Household debt to disposable income, shown in Figure 4,
remained below 70 percent until 1985. In the 1980s and 1990s,
the debt-to-income ratio grew at a compound annual growth
rate of less than 1.25 percent. By the end of the 1990s, it was still
below 95 percent. Since 2000, the ratio has increased at a compound
annual growth rate in excess of 5 percent. The top line
in Figure 4 shows the steep upward trend since the beginning
of 2000. Today this ratio is near 122 percent. The pattern of the
ratio of mortgage debt to income, the lower line in Figure 4,
mirrors the pattern of the total debt-to-income ratio.
Recent borrowing by the household sector has reached
unprecedented levels. Figure 5 shows the household sector’s borrowing
as a percent of its disposable income. During the 1990s,
borrowing by households fell to normal levels, but from 2000
onwards, borrowing as a percent of income has grown rapidly.
In the third quarter of 2005, it reached an historic high of
13.67 percent. In 2004, the household sector borrowed $1.01
trillion. In the first three quarters of 2005, the household sector
borrowed $831 billion. This contrasts with the period prior
to 2000, during which the household sector never borrowed
more than $487.5 billion in a year.
4Despite low interest rates, which effectively reduce debt
payments, debt-service burdens have reached record highs.
Figure 6 shows the trend in the debt-payments-to-disposablepersonal-
income ratio. Since 2000, the debt-service ratio has
The Levy Economics Institute of Bard College
5been well above 12 percent. In the third quarter of 2005, the
ratio hit a record 13.55 percent.
Evidence from the Flow of Funds data suggests household
liabilities have risen more rapidly than household financial assets.
Furthermore, the liability side has grown so fast that the balance
sheets of the household sector continue to deteriorate. Figure 7
shows the overall household sector’s financial-asset-to-liability
ratio, which in the third quarter of 2005 hit an historic low. The
effect of falling stock prices is clearly shown in the drop after
2000. Despite rapid house price appreciation, equity in real
estate as a percent of total real estate assets has fallen modestly,
as shown in Figure 8.While the ratio appears to have stabilized
since the mid 1990s, the rapid appreciation in housing prices
has had little effect.
A fall in real estate prices reduces household equity. At
the end of the third quarter of 2005, U.S. household real estate
was estimated to be worth $19.11 trillion, while mortgage debt
stood at $8.19 trillion, leaving total equity at $10.92 trillion.
Table 1 shows the potential effect of a drop in national housing
prices on household equity. A 5 percent drop would lead to
a $960 billion dollar loss in equity. A 10 percent drop would
reduce it by $1.91 trillion dollars. A 20 percent drop would
eliminate $3.82 trillion dollars in equity, representing a 35 percent
loss. This suggests that given the highly leveraged position
of households, even a modest drop in housing prices would
reduce their wealth considerably.
Rising home prices and low interest rates have stimulated
many homeowners to use cash-out refinancing for consumption
spending. The percentage of Freddie Mac refinanced loans
that had higher new loan amounts was 74 and 72 percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
A. New levels in trillions of dollars
Household real estate 19.11 18.15 17.20 16.24 15.29 14.33
Household mortgage debt 8.19 8.19 8.19 8.19 8.19 8.19
Household equity 10.92 9.96 9.01 8.05 7.10 6.14
B. Loss in trillions of dollars 0.00 0.96 1.91 2.87 3.82 4.78
C. New level of household equity
as percent of household real estate 57.14 54.89 52.38 49.58 46.43 42.86
Sources:
Flow of Funds and authors’ calculationsPercent Drop
55
60
65
70
75
80
1955 1961 1967 1973 1979 1985 1991 1997 2003
Figure 8
Real Estate
Household Equity as a Ratio to Total HouseholdSource:
Federal Reserve Flow of FundsTable 1
Estimated Effect of a Drop in Housing Prices on Household EquityDespite the increase in measures that suggest higher risk,
interest rates have fallen steadily and remain low. Figure 9
shows nominal interest rates for mortgages. Currently mortgage
rates are near 30-year lows.
Until recently, homeowners typically chose to finance their
homes with fixed-rate, 30-year mortgages. Homeowners didn’t
need to worry about being exposed to external events that might
affect their payment obligations. Interest-only loans were
uncommon, and variable-rate mortgages were less popular. The
nontraditional mortgages of today are different from past mortgages
in that debt-service requirements can rise unexpectedly.
When interest rates rise or when interest-only periods elapse,
payment obligations rise.Homeowners may be forced to reduce
their spending to meet the increased payment obligations. Some
may be forced to sell their homes. The volume of homes for sale
could grow because of recent trends in nontraditional mortgages
putting further downward pressure on housing prices.
6
Strategic Analysis, January 2006respectively for the second and third quarters of 2005 (Freddie
Mac 2005). For the previous three quarters, the percentage was
close to 60 percent. This contrasts sharply with the data for
2003, in which roughly 40 percent of the loans that were refinanced
had higher loan amounts. The median time elapsed to
refinance has dropped considerably from the late 1990s, when
loans where being refinanced nearly every five years. In recent
years, the median refinancing period has dropped to two and
one-half years. In the mid to late 1990s, the volume of cash-out
refinancing from Freddie Mac ranged from $21.7 to $72.4 billion.
Since 2001, the volume of cash-out refinancing has risen
dramatically. In 2001, $135.5 billion was cashed out. Cash-out
refinancing from Freddie Mac amounted to $170.5 billion in
2002, $224.4 billion in 2003, and $182 billion in 2004.Much of
this cash-out refinancing has been made possible by the growth
in housing prices.
Households are financially stretched, and falling or flat
housing prices will reduce their capacity to borrow and spend.
A series of missteps may have contributed to the excessive
growth in housing prices, household borrowing, and household
spending in recent years. In February 2004, Federal Reserve
Chairman Alan Greenspan, in a speech to credit unions, suggested
that traditional mortgages were costing American homeowners
tens of thousands of dollars. He counseled homeowners
to finance their homes with adjustable-rate mortgages. Subsequent
to Mr. Greenspan’s speech, many U.S. households financed their
homes with nontraditional adjustable-rate mortgages. In 2004,
47.8 percent of homes purchased in California were bought with
interest-only adjustable-rate mortgages (Streitfeld 2005).
Interest-only loans were used in about one-third of all purchases
nationally (Streitfeld 2005).While interest-only mortgages allow
the homeowners to defer principal payments for a number of
years, they still have to pay the full interest owed. The interestonly
mortgages delay the amortization of loans and subject
homeowners to higher future payment obligations.
5Anecdotal evidence suggests that falling credit standards
have played a role in pushing housing prices higher. Of home
buyers who financed their home purchases in the first six
months of 2005, more than 38 percent made down payments
of 5 percent or less of the purchase price. In 2000, a little over
30 percent purchased their homes with so little down (Christie
2005). Similarly, the percentage of buyers paying 20 percent
down declined from 39.1 percent in 2000 to 33.7 percent in the
first six months of 2005.
4
8
12
16
20
1972 1976 1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004
Percent
Figure 9
Mortgages
Nominal Interest Rates for 30-Year Fixed-RateSource:
Federal Reserve1
3
5
7
9
1973 1979 1985 1991 1997 2003
-4
0
4
8
12
Figure 10
Household Borrowing and Home PricesHousehold Borrowing as a Percent of GDP (Left Scale)
Growth Rate of Real Home Prices (Right Scale)
Sources:
and BEA
Percent
Federal Reserve Flow of Funds, National Association of Realtors,There is a positive correlation between household borrowing
and the growth in real home prices. Figure 10 shows
household borrowing as a percent of GDP and the real growth
in home prices since 1970. The two paths follow one another
closely. The peaks in housing prices are nearly matched by
peaks in household borrowing. Similarly, the troughs in real
home prices are nearly matched by troughs in household
borrowing. The late 1970s experienced rapid growth in both
real home prices and borrowing. Lower household borrowing
followed falling housing prices in the early 1980s.
Around the world, where housing markets have declined,
output growth has slowed. In the Netherlands, house prices
appreciated through the 1990s before stalling in 2002. This was
followed by a recession (Cave 2005). In Britain, house prices
appreciated for a decade before stalling last year. GDP in Britain
is currently growing at less than 2 percent. In Australia, house
prices have started to stall, and household consumption has
slowed (Cave 2005). Similarly, in other countries, consumptionled
growth is being impaired by slowdowns in housing prices.
Next, we explore the implications of plausible changes in
housing prices on the projected growth path of the internaland
external-sector balances of the U.S. economy.We align our
key model variables to the path projected by the Congressional
Budget Office (CBO) budget projection (August 2005) and create
a CBO Scenario with which we compare alternative scenarios.
The CBO Scenario entails a rise in government expenditures
and tax revenues in the last quarter of 2005 and a stabilization
of government deficits thereafter. It also assumes a
moderate increase in interest rates in 2006, followed by stable
rates. In addition to the variables projected by the CBO, we
assume that house prices continue to rise relative to a general
price index of private expenditure, following a moderate trend.
We keep exchange rates constant at their current (December
2005) level for our five-year simulation period.
The assumptions above mean that both the public sector
and the external sector will not provide additional stimulus to
growth. We believe stable exchange rates will not reverse the
trend in the U.S. current account deficit. The latest figures give
credence to our view. Only increased private spending relative to
income is left to stimulate GDP.We therefore adjust our assumptions
on household borrowing so that GDP growth in our model
replicates the CBO estimates.We find that in order for GDP to
follow the growth path projected by the CBO between 2005 and
2010, household borrowing must rise at an unsustainable pace,
driving the debt-to-income ratio of the household sector to
unprecedented levels. This translates into a private-sector deficit
as a percent of GDP that grows to over 4 percent by 2008. The
corresponding current account deficit as a percent of GDP
grows to over 8 percent by 2008. The government deficit stabilizes
below 4 percent of GDP, as depicted in Figure 11.
In order to estimate the impact of a drop in house prices,
we assume that house prices decline following a pattern similar
to the downturn that occurred during the early 1980s. We call
this the Slow-Growth Scenario. This assumption implies a drop
in the price of houses relative to a general price index of about 8
percent over a three-year period. We assume the slowdown
starts in the first quarter of 2006, but we have no strong position
on the timing of the slowdown, which may start later. Figure 12
shows the projected paths of real-housing-price growth rates for
a Slow-Growth Scenario, compared to the CBO Scenario.
6The Levy Economics Institute of Bard College
7-8
-4
0
4
8
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010
Figure 11
CBO Scenario: Main Sector BalancesPercent of GDP
Government Deficit
Private Sector Balance
Current Account Balance
Sources:
BEA and authors’ calculations-8
0
8
16
1970 1976 1982 1988 1994 2000 2006
Figure 12
Real Median Price of Existing Family HomesSources:
CBO Scenario
Slow
Annual Growth Rate
National Association of Realtors, BEA, and authors’ calculations-Growth ScenarioMuch of the household borrowing of the last few years has
been made possible by rising housing prices. We assume that
borrowing will revert to earlier patterns as house price appreciation
reverses. In this alternative scenario, household borrowing
slowly declines and household debt as a share of GDP stabilizes
by the end of the simulation period. Borrowing and debt as a
percent of GDP are shown in Figures 13 and 14. Under these
assumptions, the impact on GDP growth is substantial. If housing
prices decline in a pattern similar to that of the early 1980s,
and household borrowing declines slowly back to 2000 levels,we
calculate the cumulative drop in GDP over the simulation
period to be over 5 percent, compared with the CBO Scenario.
In the CBO Scenario sustained growth is fueled by private
expenditure, which together with stable government deficits
imply a rising foreign deficit reaching 8 percent of GDP by 2008,
as shown previously in Figure 11. But we think the continued
deterioration of the private-sector balance is less plausible, given
the already high debt-to-income ratios of households. Under
our alternative assumptions about housing prices and borrowing,
the private sector slowly moves back to balance. This is
shown in Figure 15.
In our Slow-Growth Scenario, no assumptions are made
about changing government expenditure. Falling GDP implies
falling tax revenues, which in turn increases general government
deficits as a percent of GDP. The U.S. current account
balance stabilizes, because lower private expenditure and GDP
growth also imply lower imports.
According to our projections, the return to balance of the private
sector slows growth in output,which translates into increased
unemployment.Unless action is taken to stop the drop in demand
for domestically produced goods and services, the increase in
unemployment stemming from the slowdown in house prices and
borrowing can only be countered by fiscal policy.
A third scenario, the Fiscal-Policy Scenario, is envisioned
in which there is an increase in general government spending
to counterbalance the reduced demand from the drop in private
expenditure (Godley et al. 2005).
Under this scenario, our estimates show the government
deficit reaching 10 percent of GDP by the end of the simulation
period just to keep unemployment at the same level as in the
CBO Scenario. This is shown in Figure 16. Faster growth in GDP
and income sustains the adjustment process for the privatesector
balance, which returns to surplus, but growth in demand
increases imports, and the current account balance deteriorates.
8
Strategic Analysis, January 2006 Percent of GDPSources:
Federal Reserve, BEA, and authors’ calculationsFigure 13
Household Borrowing0
5
10
15
20
1970 1976 1982 1988 1994 2000 2006
CBO S
cenarioSl
ow-Growth Scenario50
70
90
110
130
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010
Percent of GDP
Figure 14
Household Debt OutstandingSources:
CBO S
Federal Reserve, BEA, and authors’ calculationscenarioSl
ow-Growth Scenario-8
-4
0
4
8
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010
Figure 15
Slow-Growth Scenario: Main Sector BalancesPercent of GDP
Government Deficit
Private
Current Account Balance
-Sector BalanceSources:
BEA and authors’ calculationsThe Levy Economics Institute of Bard College
9Our projections in Figure 16 reflect recent data on household
debt, which has substantially increased in the third quarter of
2005, and trade figures that show a larger than expected deterioration
in the trade balance. If policies aimed at redressing U.S.
imbalances are postponed, the costs of adjustment will increase.
In this scenario, we have shown that fiscal policy aimed at sustaining
growth and employment implies a government deficit
that may not be politically feasible. The remaining alternative, as
pointed out in our previous strategic analyses, is policies aimed
at addressing the U.S. trade imbalance.
Our analysis and simulations suggest that much of the
recent growth in GDP can be attributed to house price appreciation
and private-sector borrowing. In our view, the projection
for sustained GDP growth expected by the Congressional
Budget Office depends on rising house prices and sustaining
the current borrowing trends of households. As we have seen,
the development and promotion of unconventional mortgages
and the loosening of credit standards over the last few years
have enabled unprecedented borrowing by households.
Despite the rapid appreciation in home prices, the financial
position of households has deteriorated. The economic trends
we have discussed, including dramatic home price appreciation
and unprecedented growth of borrowing relative to income by
households, cannot continue indefinitely.
Government Deficit
Private-Sector Balance
Current Account Balance
Sources:
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
BEA and authors’ calculationsFigure 16
Fiscal-Policy Scenario: Main Sector BalancesPercent of GDP
Notes
1. Landlords have operating expenses such as property taxes,
management fees, and repairs that make their income from
rental properties less than the rent they receive. Since rent is
always greater than earnings, the price-to-rent ratio is
always less than the corresponding price-to-earning ratio.
Direct comparison of real estate with other asset classes,
such as stocks, cannot be made using stock-flow ratios such
as the price-to-rent ratio unless the appropriate expenses
are accounted for. However, examining the price-to-rent
ratio through time can provide a useful reference point for
evaluating when home prices appear high or low.
2. For this figure, we use data reported from the Joint Center
for Housing Studies of Harvard University (2005). For
housing prices, we use the estimates from the National
Association of Realtors for the median existing singlefamily
home indexed to 2004 prices reported in Table A-1.
For rental rates, we use the contract rental costs reported in
Table A-2. We adjust these from 2001 to 2004 prices and
annualize them. Had we adjusted for vacancy rates, the
recent upward movement would be more pronounced.
3. For much of the empirical work that follows, we use the
Flow of Funds Household and Nonprofit Organization
Sector. Since nonprofit organizations represent only a small
portion of this sector, we included them in what we call the
household sector.
4. During the 1990s, borrowing as a percent of income ranged
from 2.6 percent to 8.2 percent. Since that time, borrowing
as a percent of income has been greater than 7.53 percent
in every quarter. In 2004 and 2005, it was above 10 percent
in every quarter.
5. Other types of nontraditional loans that lower monthly
payments, such as the 40-year mortgage, have grown in
popularity (“40-Year Mortgages Hit the Mainstream,”
Bankrate.com, 2005). http://moneycentral.msn.com/content/
Banking/Homefinancing/P119865.asp
6. Our measure is obtained from the annual growth rate
of the ratio between the “median price of existing singlefamily
homes” and the deflator for private expenditure. The
former measure is published by the National Association of
Realtors and has been seasonally adjusted.
——— 2005b. “Reflections on Central Banking.” Speech at a
symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City, Jackson Hole,Wyoming, August 26.
——— 2004c. “Economic Outlook and Current Fiscal Issues.”
Testimony before the Committee on the Budget, U.S.
House of Representatives, February 25.
——— 2004a. “The Mortgage Market and Consumer Debt.”
Remarks at America’s Community Bankers annual convention,
Washington, D.C., October 19.
——— 2004b. “Understanding Household Debt Obligations.”
Remarks at the Credit Union National Association
Governmental Affairs Conference, Washington, D.C.,
February 23.
——— 2003. “Home Mortgage Market.” Remarks before the
annual convention of the Independent Community Bankers
of America, Orlando, Florida (via satellite), March 4.
Hagerty, James R., and Ruth Simon. 2005. “Mortgage Risk: A
Hot Export.”
Joint Center for Housing Studies of Harvard University. 2005.
“The State of the Nation’s Housing: 2005.” www.jchs.harvard.
edu/publications/markets/son2005/son2005.pdf.
Kohn, Donald L. 2005. “Imbalances in the U.S. Economy.”
Remarks at the 15th Annual Hyman P. Minsky Conference,
The Levy Economics Institute, Annandale-on-
Hudson, New York, April 22.
Large, Andrew. 2004. “Puzzles in Today’s Economy: The Build-
Up of Household Debt.” Speech at the Association of
Corporate Treasurers’ annual conference, Newport,Wales,
United Kingdom,March 23.
Leamer, Edward E. 2003. “Bubble Trouble?: Your Home Has a
P/E Ratio Too.” UCLA Anderson Forecast. Los Angeles:
University of California, Los Angeles.
Leonhardt, David, and Motoko Rich. 2005. “Slowing Is Seen in
Housing Prices in Hot Markets.”
Mankiw, N. Gregory, and David N. Weil. 1990. “The Baby
Boom, the Baby Bust, and the Housing Market.”Working
Paper No. 2794. Cambridge, Massachusetts: National
Bureau of Economic Research.
McCarthy, Jonathan, and Richard W. Peach. 2004. “Are Home
Prices the Next ‘Bubble’?”
Economic Policy Review
National Association of Realtors. 2005. “Housing Affordability
Index.” www.realtor.org/research.nsf/pages/HousingInx?
OpenDocument.
Wall Street Journal, September 22.New York Times, October 4.Federal Reserve Bank of New York10:3: 1–17.10
Strategic Analysis, January 2006References
Baker, Dean. 2002. “The Run-Up in Home Prices: Is It Real or
Is It Another Bubble?” Center for Economic and Policy
Research, August 5.
Bankrate.com. 2005. moneycentral. msn.com/content/Banking/
Homefinancing/P119865.asp.
Bollard, Alan. 2004. “Asset Prices and Monetary Policy.”
Address by Governor of the Reserve Bank of New Zealand
to the Canterbury Employers’ Chamber of Commerce,
Christchurch, New Zealand, January 30.
Case, Karl E., Robert J. Shiller, Christopher J. Mayer, and John
M. Quigley. 2003. “Is There a Bubble in the Housing
Market?”
299–362.
Cave, Friederike Tiesenhausen. 2005. “Housing: Strong Market
May Well Be Built on Sand.”
Christie, Les. 2005. “Home Buyers Pay Less Down, Increase
Risk.”
Congressional Budget Office (CBO). 2005. “Current Budget
Projections.” www.cbo.gov/showdoc.cfm?index=1944&
sequence=0.
Del Negro, Marco, and Christopher Otrok. 2005. “Monetary
Policy and the House Price Boom across the U.S. States.”
Working Paper No. 2005-24. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta.
Freddie Mac. 2005.“Cash-Out Refinance Activity Rises in Second
Quarter 2005.” www.freddiemac.com/news/archives/rates/
2005/2qupb05.html.
——— 2005. “Cash-Out Refinance Activity Strong in Third
Quarter 2005.” www.freddiemac.com/news/archives/rates/
2005/3qupb05.html.
Glaeser, Edward L., Joseph Gyourko, and Raven E. Saks. 2005.
“Why Have Housing Prices Gone Up?” Discussion Paper
No. 2061. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard Institute of
Economic Research.
Godley, Wynne, Dimitri B. Papadimitriou, Claudio H. Dos
Santos, and Gennaro Zezza. 2005.
Her Creditors: Can the Symbiosis Last?
Annandale-on-Hudson, New York: The Levy Economics
Institute.
Gramlich, Edward M. 2004. Remarks at the Financial Services
Roundtable annual housing policy meeting,Chicago,May 21.
Greenspan, Alan. 2005a. “Mortgage Banking.” Remarks to the
American Bankers Association annual convention, Palm
Desert, California (via satellite), September 26.
Norris, Floyd. 2005. “Easy Credit in Mortgages May Backfire.”
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2003:2:Financial Times, October 6.CNNMoney, August 16.The United States andStrategic Analysis.New York Times,
Papadimitriou, Dimitri B., Anwar M. Shaikh, Claudio H. Dos
Santos, and Gennaro Zezza. 2002.
August 26.Is Personal Debt Sustainable?Strategic Analysis. Annandale-on-Hudson, New York:
The Levy Economics Institute.
Shaikh, Anwar M., Dimitri B. Papadimitriou, Claudio H. Dos
Santos, and Gennaro Zezza. 2003.
Growth: A Reprieve But Not a Pardon.
Annandale-on-Hudson, New York: The Levy Economics
Institute.
Simon,Ruth, and James R.Hagerty. 2005.“How American Lenders
Shelter Themselves.”
Srejber, Eva. 2002. “Inflation Targeting and Bubbles.” Speech at
Adam Smith seminar, Paris, July 9.
Streitfeld, David. 2005. “They’re In—But Not Home Free.”
Angeles Times,
U.S. Bureau of the Census. 2005. Current Population Survey/
Housing Vacancy Survey, Series H-111. www.census.gov/
hhes/www/housing/hvs/historic/histtab1.html.
Deficits, Debts, andStrategic Analysis.Wall Street Journal, September 22.LosApril 3.Recent Levy Institute Publications
STRATEGIC ANALYSES
Are Housing Prices, Household Debt, and Growth Sustainable?
DIMITRI B. PAPADIMITRIOU, EDWARD CHILCOTE,
andGENNARO ZEZZA
January 2006
The United States and Her Creditors: Can the
Symbiosis Last?
WYNNE GODLEY, DIMITRI B. PAPADIMITRIOU,
CLAUDIO H. DOS SANTOS
, and GENNARO ZEZZASeptember 2005
How Fragile Is the U.S. Economy?
DIMITRI B. PAPADIMITRIOU, ANWAR M. SHAIKH
,CLAUDIO H. DOS SANTOS
, and GENNARO ZEZZAMarch 2005
Prospects and Policies for the U.S. Economy: Why Net
Exports Must Now Be the Motor for U.S. Growth
WYNNE GODLEY, ALEX IZURIETA,
and GENNARO ZEZZAAugust 2004
LEVY INSTITUTE MEASURE OF ECONOMIC WELL-BEING
Interim Report 2005: The Effects of Government Deficits and
the 2001–02 Recession on Well-Being
EDWARD N. WOLFF
, AJIT ZACHARIAS, and HYUNSUB KUMMay 2005
Economic Well-Being in U.S. Regions and the Red and
Blue States
EDWARD N. WOLFF
, and AJIT ZACHARIASMarch 2005
How Much Does Public Consumption Matter for
Well-Being?
EDWARD N. WOLFF
, AJIT ZACHARIAS, and ASENA CANERDecember 2004
How Much Does Wealth Matter for Well-Being?
Alternative Measures of Income from Wealth
EDWARD N. WOLFF
, AJIT ZACHARIAS, and ASENA CANERSeptember 2004
Levy Institute Measure of Economic Well-Being:
United States, 1989, 1995, 2000, and 2001
EDWARD N. WOLFF
, AJIT ZACHARIAS, and ASENA CANERMay 2004
Levy Institute Measure of Economic Well-Being:
Concept, Measurement, and Findings: United States, 1989
and 2000
EDWARD N. WOLFF
, AJIT ZACHARIAS, and ASENA CANERFebruary 2004
The Strategic Analysis and all other Levy Institute publications
are available online on the Levy Institute website,www.levy.org.
To order a Levy Institute publication, call 845-758-7700 or
202-887-8464 (in Washington,D.C.), fax 845-758-1149, e-mail
info@levy.org, write The Levy Economics Institute of Bard
College, Blithewood, PO Box 5000, Annandale-on-Hudson,
NY 12504-5000, or visit our website at www.levy.org.
The Levy Economics Institute of Bard College
12
11Strategic Analysis, January 2006NONPROFIT ORGANIZATION
U.S. POSTAGE PAID
BARD COLLEGE
The Levy Economics Institute of Bard College
Blithewood
PO Box 5000
Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000
Address Service Requested
No comments:
Post a Comment